Wonder Club world wonders pyramid logo
×

Reviews for What price incentives?

 What price incentives? magazine reviews

The average rating for What price incentives? based on 2 reviews is 4 stars.has a rating of 4 stars

Review # 1 was written on 2021-01-18 00:00:00
0was given a rating of 3 stars Jason Braswell
Had to dig this one up after an argument with somebody over externalities - both positive (e.g. 'free rider') and negative (e.g. pollution). The former are typically addressed by subsidies, the latter - by taxation. Cordato makes a good case for market-driven alternatives to dealing with externalities (e.g. well-defined and enforced property rights to address pollution). Free pdf of this book is on mises.org
Review # 2 was written on 2012-08-03 00:00:00
0was given a rating of 5 stars Ivan Jovanov
Interesting Quotes: "[A]mong the 'circumstances' which Pigou chose not to specify is the nature of property rights governing the use of the roads; but property rights are indispensable constraints for any decision involving more than one individual. Moreover, Knight was essentially correct in pointing out that if private ownership is established, "'the owner ofthe narrow road can charge for its use a toll representing its 'superiority' over the free road, [and] in accordance with the theory of rent, . . . the toll will exactly equal the ideal tax . . .' In charging the market with failure to attain the maximum social benefit while disallowing private property rights (upon which all private transactions must be based), Pigou was indeed barking up the wrong tree. To my knowledge Pigou never replied to Knight's paper, although the example of the two roads was deleted from later editions of The Economics of Welfare: the debate was over when it had barely begun. This, together with the difficult nature of Knight's paper, may explain the slow progress of social-cost analysis in spite of numerous writings on the subject. It was not until the publication of Coase's paper 36 years later that the issue at stake was again brought into academic debate." -Steven N.S. Cheung, The Myth of Social Cost -------------------------------------------------- "[A]ny government action can be speciously justified on efficiency grounds by the simple expedient of assuming that transaction costs in the market are high and that costs of governmental control are low. The use of such arbitrary (often implicit) assumptions, a routine practice in the traditional analysis of social cost, is appropriate neither for economic explanation nor for policy formulation." -Steven Cheung, the Myth of Social Cost ---------------------------------------------------- "The serious problems of the environment and conservation exist where there is common, and not private, ownership. In Africa, for example, lions have been treated in the past as common property''fair game' for anyone'with the result that their numbers have fallen drastically during the 20th century. But in the UK lions are reared and held under private ownership (in game parks and zoos), and the British lion population has boomed. Indeed, British game parks are now exporting their surplus lions'to Africa! This is 'taking coals to Newcastle' with a new twist." -John Burton, Externalities, Property Rights, and Public Policy : Private Property Rights or the Spoliation of Nature, epilogue of the Myth of Social Cost ------------------------------------------------------ "Cultivated farmland was far more extensive during the Roman era than before or after, and huge areas that have become desert were then green and plenteous. Tripolitania and Cyrenaica (the eastern Roman province) may not have been the granaries of the Roman empire, but the desert was then held far more extensively in check than under the following eras of Vandal, Berber and Arab rule. "Historical research suggests that there was no wide variation in climatic conditions to account for the rolling back of the desert in the Roman era and the long-term trend to desertification thereafter. The answer seems to lie in the errors of human beings, not in the accidents of nature. Systems of common land ownership now account for the bulk of Libyan acreage, and have done so for over fifteen hundred years, since the Vandals expelled the Romans from Libya, circa AD 455. But under Roman rule the land was extensively farmed under a system of private property rights. During the early empire it was farmed primarily by Berber peasants and other smallholders such as retired soldiers who had been granted private property rights in plots of land. Later there also emerged latifundia (large privately-owned estates) worked by Berber serf labour. With land held privately, there was incentive to conserve vegetation, rather than to treat it as a 'free good'). The benefits and costs of planting and grazing impinged upon the owner and not others: the externalities were 'internalised'" "Following the decline of Roman rule, the system of private property rights in land reverted to that of tribal ownership . . . The long-term consequences of that change in the system of property rights are written in the encroaching sands of the Libyan desert today. -John Burton, Externalities, Property Rights, and Public Policy : Private Property Rights or the Spoliation of Nature, epilogue of the Myth of Social Cost ---------------------------------------------------------------


Click here to write your own review.


Login

  |  

Complaints

  |  

Blog

  |  

Games

  |  

Digital Media

  |  

Souls

  |  

Obituary

  |  

Contact Us

  |  

FAQ

CAN'T FIND WHAT YOU'RE LOOKING FOR? CLICK HERE!!!